Iron law of prohibition
The iron law of prohibition is a term coined by Richard Cowan in 1986 which posits that as law enforcement becomes more intense, the potency of prohibited substances increases.[1] Cowan put it this way: "the harder the enforcement, the harder the drugs."[2]
This law is an application of the Alchian–Allen effect; Libertarian judge Jim Gray calls the law the "cardinal rule of prohibition", and notes that is a powerful argument for the legalization of drugs.[1][3] It is based on the premise that when drugs or alcohol are prohibited, they will be produced in black markets in more concentrated and powerful forms, because these more potent forms offer better efficiency in the business model—they take up less space in storage, less weight in transportation, and they sell for more money. Economist Mark Thornton writes that the iron law of prohibition undermines the argument in favor of prohibition, because the higher potency forms are less safe for the consumer.[4]
Findings
[edit]Thornton published research showing that the potency of marijuana increased in response to higher enforcement budgets. He later expanded this research in his dissertation to include other illegal drugs and alcohol during Prohibition in the United States (1920–1933). The basic approach is based on the Alchian and Allen Theorem. This argument says that a fixed cost (e.g. transportation fee) added to the price of two varieties of the same product (e.g. high quality red apple and a low quality red apple) results in greater sales of the more expensive variety. When applied to rum-running, drug smuggling, and blockade running the more potent products become the sole focus of the suppliers. Thornton notes that the greatest added cost in illegal sales is the avoidance of detection.[4] Thornton says that if drugs are legalized, then consumers will begin to wean themselves off the higher potency forms, for instance with cocaine users buying coca leaves, and heroin users switching to opium.[5]
The popular shift from beer to wine to hard liquor during the US Prohibition era[6] has a parallel in the narcotics trade in the late 20th century. Bulky opium was illegal, so refined heroin became more prevalent, albeit with significant risk from blood-borne disease because of injection by needle, and far greater risk of death from overdose. Marijuana was also found too bulky and troublesome to smuggle across borders, so smugglers turned to refined cocaine with its much higher potency and profit per pound.[7] Cowan wrote in 1986 that crack cocaine was entirely a product of the prohibition of drugs.[2] Clinical psychiatrist Michael J. Reznicek adds crystal meth to this list.[8] In the 2010s the iron law has been invoked to explain why heroin is displaced by fentanyl and other, even stronger, synthetic opioids.[9]
With underage drinking by teens in the U.S., one of the impacts of laws against possession of alcohol by minors is that teens tend to prefer distilled spirits, because they are easier to conceal than beer.[citation needed]
Derivation
[edit]Consider the situation where there are two substitute goods and , denoting the higher and lower quality goods with respective prices and , and where i.e. the higher quality good has a higher price. Each of these goods has a compensated demand curve (a demand curve which holds utility constant) of the form where with denoting the utility function of the consumer. Furthermore, we will also assume that income is held constant, as income effects are indeterminate in forecasting changes in demand.
Suppose that there is an associated cost that is added to each good due to transport costs. We want to know how the ratio of demand changes for the two goods based on . Taking the derivative with respect to yields
(1) |
From our assumptions, we have that the total price for each item is . Therefore, we may compute to be
We may now rewrite (1) as
(2) |
Finally, using the cross-elasticity of demand, we arrive at the following expression of the derivative
(3) |
Now, we want to show that , but seem to be stuck with elasticities that are indeterminate. However, Hicks' third law of demand[10] gives us and . To see why this is, suppose that we take a more general version of the compensated demand function with goods and compensated demand curves , for .
For a homogeneous function of degree , defined as Euler's homogeneous function theorem states that
Compensated demand functions are homogeneous of degree 0, since multiplying all prices by a constant yields the same solution to the expenditure minimization problem as the original prices. Thus, Dividing by the stock yields which establishes Hicks' third law of demand.
Using Hicks' law, (3) is rewritten as
(4) |
Suppose for the sake of contradiction that . Then, By initial assumption, our two goods are substitutes. As such, and , implying that But, this contradicts the assumption that . Thus, we conclude that . This implies that as the transport costs increase, the higher quality good will become more prevalent than the lower quality good. In the drug-specific context, as costs associated with drug enforcement increase, the more potent drug will become more prevalent in the illegal drug market.
References
[edit]- ^ a b Mosher, Clayton J.; Akins, Scott (2007). Drugs and Drug Policy: The Control of Consciousness Alteration. SAGE. pp. 308–09. ISBN 978-0761930075.
- ^ a b Cowan, Richard (December 5, 1986). "How the Narcs Created Crack: A War Against Ourselves". National Review. 38 (23): 26–34.
- ^ Gray, James P. (2001). Why Our Drug Laws Have Failed: A Judicial Indictment Of War On Drugs. Temple University Press. ISBN 978-1-56639-860-2.
- ^ a b Thornton, Mark (July 17, 1991). "Alcohol Prohibition Was A Failure". Policy Analysis. Cato. Archived from the original on December 29, 2013. Retrieved December 20, 2013.
- ^ Levinson, David (2002). Encyclopedia of Crime and Punishment. SAGE. p. 561. ISBN 076192258X.
- ^ Mendelson, Richard (2009). From Demon to Darling: A Legal History of Wine in America. University of California Press. pp. 50–51. ISBN 978-0520259430.
- ^ Healy, Gene (2008). "Drug Prohibition". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE; Cato Institute. pp. 128–29. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n81. ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024.
- ^ Reznicek, Michael J. (2012). Blowing Smoke: Rethinking the War on Drugs Without Prohibition and Rehab. Rowman & Littlefield. p. 154. ISBN 978-1442215146.
- ^ Szalavitz, Maia (26 April 2016). "Street opioids are getting deadlier. Overseeing drug use can reduce deaths [Op-Ed]". The Guardian. Retrieved 12 March 2017.
- ^ Hicks, John R. (1946). Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.
Further reading
[edit]- Thornton, Mark (1991). The Economics of Prohibition (PDF). Salt Lake City: University of Utah Press.
- Lavine, Harry; Reinarman, Craig (1991). "From Prohibition to Regulation". Milbank Quarterly. 69 (2).
- Ekelund, Robert B.; Thornton, Mark (1992). "The Union Blockade and Demoralization of the South: Relative Prices in the Confederacy". Social Science Quarterly. 73 (4): 890–902.
- Thornton, Mark (1998). "The Potency of Illegal Drugs". Journal of Drug Issues. 28 (3): 725–40. doi:10.1177/002204269802800309. S2CID 68070362.
- Thornton, Mark (January 20, 2011). "What Explains Crystal Meth?". Mises Daily.